\
BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you
consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it
will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free
access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[New search]
[Printable RTF version]
[Buy ICLR report: [1998] QB 781]
[Buy ICLR report: [1998] 2 WLR 893]
[Help]
IN
THE SUPREME COURT OF JUDICATURE
CCRTF
97/0880 CMS2
COURT
OF APPEAL (CIVIL DIVISION)
ON
APPEAL FROM THE READING COUNTY COURT
(His
Honour Judge Haque)
Royal
Courts of Justice,
Strand,
London WC2
Friday,
27th February 1998
B
e f o r e :
LORD
JUSTICE KENNEDY
LORD
JUSTICE MILLETT and
LORD
JUSTICE HUTCHISON
---------------
THAI
TRADING (A FIRM)
Plaintiffs/Respondents
-v-
MRS
MARGERY TAYLOR
Defendant
and
MR
WILFRID DAVID TAYLOR
(of
Taylors Solicitors, Caversham)
Appellant/Appellant
---------------
Computer
Aided Transcript of the Palantype Notes of
Smith
Bernal Reporting Limited
180
Fleet Street London EC4A 2HD
Tel:
0171 421 4040 Fax: 0171 831 8838
(Official
Shorthand Writers to the Court)
---------------
DR
J WILLIAMS
(instructed by Messrs Taylors of Caversham, Reading) appeared on behalf of the
Appellant Appellant.
THE
RESPONDENT PLAINTIFFS MR A BEARD and MR T BEARD (assisted by MR HEAVER, their
McKenzie Friend)
appeared in person.
---------------
J
U D G M E N T
(As
Approved by the Court)
(Crown
Copyright)
Friday,
27th February 1998
LORD
JUSTICE MILLETT:
1 In
June 1991 Mrs Taylor ordered a four-poster Thai carved bed from the Plaintiffs
for the price of £2,500. She paid a deposit of £1,500. The bed was
delivered, but it did not match Mrs Taylor’s expectations. She rejected
it and refused to pay anything more. The Plaintiffs brought proceedings in the
Reading County Court for the unpaid balance of the purchase price and Mrs
Taylor counterclaimed for the return of the money she had paid.
2
The case was a small, run-of-the-mill county court case and should have been
disposed of speedily and with relatively little expense. Unfortunately it had a
protracted history and involved a number of court appearances, with the result
that the present appeal, which relates to Mrs Taylor’s costs, is
concerned with a sum which is out of all proportion to the amount originally in
issue.
3 Mrs
Taylor won her case. The Plaintiffs’ action was dismissed and Mrs Taylor
obtained judgment on her counterclaim. The Plaintiffs were ordered to pay Mrs
Taylor’s costs up to 22nd March 1993 and from 25th January 1994 with no
order as to costs for the intervening period. This reflected the fact that Mrs
Taylor had eventually succeeded on a point not taken before the District Judge.
4 In
the course of taxation the Plaintiffs challenged the amount claimed to be due
from them. Mrs Taylor had paid the disbursements out of her own money and the
Plaintiffs did not dispute their liability for these. But they disputed any
further liability on the ground that Mrs Taylor was not legally liable to pay
her solicitor his profit costs. It is a well settled principle that a
successful party who has been awarded his costs can recover by way of indemnity
only the costs which he is legally liable to pay to his own solicitor or in the
case of disbursements to third parties. The principle was established in Gundry
v Sainsbury
[1910] 1 KB 645, where the successful party was unable to obtain an
order for costs because his solicitor had agreed to act for him without reward.
5 The
circumstances which give rise to the allegation that Mrs Taylor was not legally
liable to pay her solicitor’s profit costs are as follows. Mrs
Taylor’s husband is a solicitor practising under the firm name of
Taylors. He is a sole practitioner. Mrs Taylor works for the firm as an
accounts clerk. She naturally employed the firm to act for her in the
proceedings brought against her, and it represented her throughout the course
of the litigation.
6 Mrs
Taylor deposed in an affidavit as follows:
“There
was no agreement either expressly or by implication between myself and my
husband, acting as my solicitor, that he would not render bills to me. Upon the
recovery of costs awarded to me they will be dealt with in the same way as with
any client recovering costs following litigation and a bill will be raised
covering these costs.”
7 The
Judge (His Honour Judge Nigel Hague QC) accepted Mrs Taylor’s evidence
that there was no express agreement between her and her husband in regard to
her costs, but he found that there was an understanding that she would not pay
anything if she lost. He said:
“...the
commonsense of the matter points strongly to the conclusion that Taylors would
only be paid by Mrs Taylor if and to the extent that she won the litigation and
could recover the costs from the Plaintiffs. I cannot believe that Taylors
intended or expected to be paid if she lost. The notions that in those
circumstances Taylors would have billed Mrs Taylor and that she would have paid
such a bill (whether out of her own earnings or savings or out of money
provided by her husband), thereby increasing Mr Taylor’s profits and his
income tax liability, are to my mind fanciful...
“For
those reasons, although I reject the Plaintiffs’ first contention that
Mrs Taylor was under no obligation to pay Taylors in any circumstances, I
accept their second contention. I find that there was an understanding between
Taylors and Mrs Taylor that she would not be liable to them for any profit
costs except in the event of success in the litigation and an order for costs
in her favour, when she would be liable for their normal profit costs.”
8 There
is no appeal from this finding, which was based on inference from the primary
facts. In my opinion the facts did not warrant the inference that there was any
understanding as to Mrs Taylor’s legal liability in respect of costs. To
my mind the only legitimate inference was that, while Mrs Taylor’s legal
liability for costs was not affected, save in unforeseen circumstances neither
party expected Mr Taylor to demand payment or enforce her liability unless she
won her case and to the extent that she recovered costs from the Plaintiffs.
9 In
a judgment for which I should wish to express my respectful admiration the
Judge pointed out that, if the law relating to the recovery of contingent fees
be put on one side, the so-called indemnity principle did not avail the
Plaintiffs. Even if there was an express agreement that Mr Taylor would be paid
his profit costs only if Mrs Taylor won her case, she would still be entitled
to be indemnified against a legal liability which had been incurred in the
events which had happened. The fact that she would have incurred no liability
in a different event which had not happened would not affect this.
10 Had
he felt free to do so, the Judge would have held that the agreement between Mrs
Taylor and her husband which he had found was entered into was a valid and
enforceable agreement. But he reluctantly concluded that he was bound by
authority, in particular the decisions of the Divisional Court in British
Waterways Board v Norman (1993) 22 HLR 232 and of Garland J in Aratra Potato Co
Ltd v Taylor Johnson Garrett [1995] 4 All ER 695, to hold that the agreement,
being an agreement for a contingent fee, was contrary to public policy and so
void. Those decisions also showed that the consequence was that there was no
legal liability on Mrs Taylor to pay Taylors’ profit costs, and hence by
virtue of the indemnity principle no liability on the Plaintiffs to pay such
costs.
11 The
Judge felt the injustice of the result which he was constrained by authority to
reach. He subjected the two decisions to which I have referred to respectful
criticism, but rightly held that he was bound by them. We are not so bound, and
are free to examine the underlying principles afresh.
12 Mrs
Taylor has appealed the Judge’s decision, but has no financial interest
in the result of the appeal. Accordingly Mr Taylor has been joined as an
additional party to the appeal and argument has been presented on his behalf.
The
Solicitors Act 1974
13 It
should be observed at the outset that there is nothing in the Solicitors Act
1974 which prohibits the charging of contingent fees. Section 59(2) merely
provides that nothing in the Act shall give validity to arrangements of the
kind there specified. It does not legitimise such arrangements if they are
otherwise unlawful, but neither does it make them unlawful if they are
otherwise lawful.
14 The
Solicitors Practice Rules 1987 by contrast provide that a solicitor engaged in
any contentious business shall not enter into any arrangement to receive a
contingency fee, that is to say a fee payable only in the event of success in
the proceeding. There is now an exception for conditional fee agreements which
satisfy the requirements of the
Courts and Legal Services Act 1990. Except as
there provided, therefore, it is unprofessional conduct for a solicitor to
enter into any agreement even for his normal fee where this is dependent on
achieving a successful result in litigation. The Plaintiffs placed much
reliance on this. But the fact that a professional rule prohibits a particular
practice does not of itself make the practice contrary to law: see Picton Jones
& Co. v Arcadia Developments Ltd. [1989] 1 EGLR 42. Moreover, the
Solicitors Rules are based on a perception of public policy derived from
judicial decisions the correctness of which is in question in this appeal.
Maintenance
and champerty
15 The
law governing contingent fees outside the scope of the
Courts and Legal
Services Act 1990 is derived from the public policy relating to champerty and
maintenance. Until 1967 these were both criminal and tortious. Following the
recommendation of the Law Commission the Criminal Law Act 1967 provided that
they should no longer be either criminal or tortious. Section 14(2) of the Act,
however, preserved the rule of the common law that they are contrary to public
policy.
16 Maintenance
was described by Lord Denning MR in Re Trepca Mines (No. 2) [1963] 1 Ch. 199,
219 as
“improperly
stirring up litigation and strife by giving aid to one party to bring or defend
a claim without just cause or excuse.”
Champerty
was described by Scrutton LJ in Ellis v Torrington [1920] 1 KB 399, 412 as
“...only
a particular form of maintenance where the person who maintains takes as a
reward a share in the property recovered.”
17 This
last formulation does not assume that the maintenance is unlawful. There can be
no champerty if there is no maintenance; but there can still be champerty even
if the maintenance is not unlawful. The public policy which informs the two
doctrines is different and allows for different exceptions. In examining the
present scope of the doctrine, it must be remembered that public policy is not
static. In recent times the roles of maintenance and champerty have been
progressively redefined and narrowed in scope. The current position is stated
by the decision of the House of Lords in Giles v Thompson
[1994] 1 AC 142, 161.
Maintenance
18 The
policy underlying the law of maintenance was described by Fletcher-Moulton LJ
in British Cash and Parcel Conveyors Ltd. v Lamson Store Service Co. Ltd.
[1908] 1 KB 1006 at 1015 in terms which were approved by Lord Mustill in Giles
v Thompson as follows:
“It
is directed against wanton and officious intermeddling with the disputes of
others in which the [maintainer] has no interest whatever, and where the
assistance he renders to one or the other party is without justification or
excuse.”
The
language and the policy which it describes are redolent of the ethos of an
earlier age when litigation was regarded as an evil and recourse to law was
discouraged. It rings oddly in our ears today when access to justice is
regarded as a fundamental human right which ought to be readily available to all.
19 But
even in former times maintenance was permissible when the maintainer had a
legitimate interest in the outcome of the suit. This was not confined to cases
where he had a financial or commercial interest in the result. It extended to
other cases where social, family or other ties justified the maintainer in
supporting the litigation. In Neville v London Express Newspaper Ltd. [1919] AC
368 at p. 389 Lord Haldane said:
“Such
an interest is held to be possessed when in litigation a master assists his
servant, or a servant his master, or help is given to an heir, or a near
relative, or to a poor man out of charity, to maintain a right which he might
otherwise lose.”
In
Bradlaugh v Newdegate
(1883) 11 QBD 1 at p. 11 Lord Coleridge CJ spoke of
“...the
interest which consanguinity or affinity to the suitor give to the man who aids
him, or the interest which arises from the connection of the parties, eg. as
master and servant....”
In
Condliffe v Hislop [1996] 1 WLR 753 this Court held that it was not unlawful
for a mother to provide limited funds to finance her bankrupt son’s
action for defamation.
20
In the present case the Plaintiffs do not contend that Mr Taylor was guilty of
unlawfully maintaining his wife’s suit. He was doubly justified in doing
so; the suitor was both his wife and his employee.
Champerty
21 In
Giles v Thompson Lord Mustill cited with approval Fletcher-Moulton LJ’s
description of maintenance to which I have already referred, and added:
“This
was a description of maintenance. For champerty there must be added the notion
of a division of the spoils.”
22 The
public policy which underlies the doctrine of champerty was described by Lord
Denning MR in Re Trepca Mines Ltd. (No.2) at pp. 219-20:
“The
reason why the common law condemns champerty is because of the abuses to which
it may give rise. The common law fears that the champertous maintainer might be
tempted, for his own personal gain, to inflame the damages, to suppress
evidence, or even to suborn witnesses.”
Describing
champerty as “a particularly obnoxious form of maintenance” in
Trendtex Trading v Credit Suisse [1980] 1 QB 629,654, Lord Denning reserved his
particular condemnation for the lawyer who charged a contingency fee, that is
to say, a fee which would be payable only if his client was successful. He said:
“[Champerty]
exists when the maintainer seeks to make a profit out of another man’s
action - by taking the proceeds of it, or a part of them, for himself. Modern
public policy condemns champerty in a lawyer whenever he seeks to recover - not
only his proper costs - but also a portion of the damages for himself;
or
when he conducts a case on the basis that he is to be paid if he wins but not
if he loses
“(my
emphasis).
23
Lord Denning was there repeating what he had said in Wallersteiner v Moir
(No.2) [1975] 1 QB 373 at p. 393:
“English
law has never sanctioned an agreement by which a lawyer is remunerated on the
basis of a “contingency fee”, that is that he gets paid the fee if
he wins, but not if he loses. Such an agreement was illegal on the ground that
it was the offence of champerty....“
Lord
Denning was prepared nevertheless to authorise the plaintiff in a derivative
action to enter into a contingency fee agreement, but the other members of the
Court (Buckley and Scarman LJJ) thought otherwise. It is, however, clear from
the judgments of the majority that they did not have in mind the charging of
normal fees contingent on success in the action. Thus Buckley LJ said at p. 402:
“Under
a contingency fee agreement the remuneration payable by the client to his
lawyer in the event of his success must be higher than it would be if the
lawyer were entitled to be remunerated, win or lose: the contingency fee must
contain an element of compensation for the risk of having done the work for
nothing. It would, it seems to me, be unfair to the opponent of a contingency
fee litigant if he were at risk of being ordered to pay higher costs to his
opponent in the event of the latter’s success in the action than would be
the case if there were no contingency fee agreement.”
24 It
is understandable that a contingency fee which entitles the solicitor to a
reward over and above his ordinary profit costs if he wins should be condemned
as tending to corrupt the administration of justice. There is no reason to
suppose that Lord Denning in Trendtex Trading v Credit Suisse or any of the
members of the Court in Wallersteiner v Moir had in mind a contingency fee
which entitles the solicitor to no more than his ordinary profit costs if he
wins. These are subject to taxation and their only vice is that they are more
than he will receive if he loses. Such a fee cannot sensibly be described as a
“division of the spoils”. The solicitor cannot obtain more than he
would without the arrangement and risks obtaining less. On the principle that
“the worker is worthy of his hire” I would regard the solicitor who
enters into such an arrangement, not as charging a fee if he wins, but rather
as agreeing to forego his fee if he loses. I question whether this should be
regarded as contrary to public policy today, if indeed it ever was.
25 In
British Waterways Board v Norman the solicitors knew that their client was on
income support, advised her to bring a private prosecution without suggesting
to her that she would have to pay anything towards the costs, and only expected
to be paid by her if she was successful and an order for costs was made against
the Board. It never occurred to the client that she would have to pay any costs
out of her own pocket. The Divisional Court held that the only possible
conclusion from these facts was that there was an understanding amounting in
law to a contract that the client would not be liable for their costs if she
lost the case. This was in the face of evidence which the magistrates accepted
that there was no contractual arrangement with the client that the solicitors
would not collect costs from her if the case was lost, that there was no
question of a contingency fee, and no agreement express or implied that the
solicitors would only be paid if successful. I doubt that the Divisional Court
was correct to conclude that there was only one possible interpretation of the
facts. It is not uncommon for solicitors to take on a case for an impecunious
client with a meritorious case, knowing that there is no realistic prospect of
recovering their costs from the client if the case is lost, without thereby
waiving their legal right to their fees in that event. As every debt collector
knows, what is legally recoverable and what is recoverable in practice are not
the same.
26 The
Divisional Court followed Lord Denning’s indication of the width of the
doctrine in Trendtex Trading v Credit Suisse. McCowan LJ explained the
rationale at p. 242 as follows:
“To
put it in a nutshell, once a lawyer has a personal interest in litigation, his
or her objectivity may be affected.”
Tuckey
J said that if it was made clear that the client was liable for costs
irrespective of the outcome of the proceedings, there could be no objection to
the solicitor agreeing that such liability need not be discharged until the
outcome of the proceedings was known. At that stage,
provided
it had not formed the basis of any prior agreement with the client
,
the solicitor could properly forego his right to be paid to the extent that any
of the costs were not recovered from the other party to the proceedings. In the
present case the Judge described this conclusion as most unsatisfactory. He
pointed out, justifiably in my opinion, that it elevates form above substance,
and invites solicitors to produce documents evidencing an agreement which both
parties know would not be enforced. I agree with the Judge’s comment that
the need for solicitors to engage in a subterfuge of this kind in order to
recover their costs in the event of a successful outcome to the litigation
shows that the underlying reasoning is unsound.
27 In
Aratra Potato Co. Ltd v Taylor Johnson Garrett [1995] 4 All ER 695 the
absurdities to which such reasoning is capable of leading were dramatically
exposed. Solicitors were engaged on a retainer which included a term that there
would be a 20% reduction from solicitor/client costs for any lost cases.
Garland J held that it was champertous and contrary to public policy for
solicitors to agree a differential fee dependent on the outcome of litigation;
that the entire retainer was unlawful; and accordingly the solicitors could not
recover their outstanding fees for work done irrespective of the outcome of the
cases and with or without the reduction. The fact that the solicitors were
seeking to recover no more (and in respect of lost cases less) than their
ordinary profit costs made no difference.
28 If
this is the law then something has gone badly wrong. It is time to step back
and consider the matter afresh in the light of modern conditions. I start with
three propositions. First, if it is contrary to public policy for a lawyer to
have a financial interest in the outcome of a suit this is because (and only
because) of the temptations to which it exposes him. At best he may lose his
professional objectivity; at worst he may be persuaded to attempt to pervert
the course of justice. Secondly, there is nothing improper in a lawyer acting
in a case for a meritorious client who to his knowledge cannot afford to pay
his costs if the case is lost: see Singh v Observer Ltd. (Note) [1989] 3 All ER
777; A Ltd v B Ltd [1996] Ch.D. 665. Not only is this not improper; it is in
accordance with current notions of the public interest that he should do so.
Thirdly, if the temptation to win at all costs is present at all, it is present
whether or not the lawyer has formally waived his fees if he loses. It arises
from his knowledge that in practice he will not be paid unless he wins. In my
judgment the reasoning in the British Waterways Board v Norman is unsound.
29 Accordingly,
either it is improper for a solicitor to act in litigation for a meritorious
client who cannot afford to pay him if he loses, or it is not improper for a
solicitor to agree to act on the basis that he is to be paid his ordinary costs
if he wins but not if he loses. I have no hesitation in concluding that the
second of these propositions represents the current state of the law.
30 I
reach this conclusion for several reasons. In the first place, I do not
understand why it is assumed that the effect of the arrangement being unlawful
is that the solicitor is unable to recover his proper costs in any
circumstances. Where the solicitor contracts for a reward over and above his
proper fees if he wins, it may well be that the whole retainer is unlawful and
the solicitor can recover nothing. But where he contracts for no more than his
proper fees if he wins, this result does not follow. There is nothing unlawful
in the retainer or in the client’s obligation to pay the
solicitor’s proper costs if he wins the case. If there is anything
unlawful, it is in the waiver or reduction of the fees if he loses. On ordinary
principles the result of holding this to be unlawful is that the client is
liable for the solicitor’s proper costs even if he loses the case. I
regard Aratra Potato Co. Ltd. v Taylor as wrongly decided.
31 In
the second place, it is in my judgment fanciful to suppose that a solicitor
will be tempted to compromise his professional integrity because he will be
unable to recover his ordinary profit costs in a small case if the case is
lost. Solicitors are accustomed to withstand far greater incentives to
impropriety than this. The solicitor who acts for a multinational company in a
heavy commercial action knows that if he loses the case his client may take his
business elsewhere. In the present case, Mr Taylor had more at stake than his
profit costs if he lost. His client was his wife; desire for domestic harmony
alone must have provided a powerful incentive to win.
32 Current
attitudes to these questions are exemplified by the passage into law of the
Courts and Legal Services Act 1990. This shows that the fear that lawyers may
be tempted by having a financial incentive in the outcome of litigation to act
improperly is exaggerated, and that there is a countervailing public policy in
making justice readily accessible to persons of modest means. Legislation was
needed to authorise the increase in the lawyer’s reward over and above
his ordinary profit costs. It by no means follows that it was needed to
legitimise the long-standing practice of solicitors to act for meritorious
clients without means, and it is in the public interest that they should
continue to do so. I observe that the author of Cook on Costs (2d. Ed) at p.
341 expresses his doubt that it is now against public policy for a solicitor to
agree with a client that he will not charge a fee unless a particular result is
achieved. I agree with him and would hold that it is not.
Conclusion
In
my judgment there is nothing unlawful in a solicitor acting for a party to
litigation to agree to forego all or part of his fee if he loses, provided that
he does not seek to recover more than his ordinary profit costs and
disbursements if he wins. I would accordingly overrule the decisions in British
Waterways Board v Norman and Aratra Potato Co. Ltd. v Taylor Johnson Garrett
and allow the appeal.
LORD
JUSTICE HUTCHISON: I agree that this appeal should be allowed for the reasons
that Lord Justice Millett has given, with which I am in complete agreement.
LORD
JUSTICE KENNEDY: I also agree.
Order: appeal
allowed with costs.
BAILII:
Copyright Policy |
Disclaimers |
Privacy Policy |
Feedback |
Donate to BAILII
URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWCA/Civ/1998/370.html