BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you
consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it
will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free
access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[New search]
[Printable RTF version]
[Help]
Irish Stock Exchange Rules [1994] IECA 335 (10th June, 1994)
Competition
Authority decision of 10 June 1994 relating to a proceeding under Section 4 of
the Competition Act, 1991
Notification
No. CA/199/92E - Irish Stock Exchange Rules in relation to dealings in Irish
Government Securities.
Decision
no. 335
Introduction
1. The
rules of the Irish Stock Exchange in relation to dealings in Irish Government
Securities (Gilts) were notified to the Competition Authority on 29 September,
1992. The notification requested a certificate, or in the event of a refusal
by the Authority to grant a certificate, a licence. On March 10 1994 the
Authority issued a Statement of Objections to the Stock Exchange indicating
that it intended to refuse its request for a certificate or licence. The
Authority specifically objected to two aspects of the rules namely those
setting minimum commissions for transactions in gilts and providing that
stockbrokers act only as agents in respect of such transactions. On 6 April
1994 the Stock Exchange indicated that it had decided not to challenge the
Authority's objections to the fixed commission regime. It indicated that it
did not accept the Authority's views on the agency rule and requested an Oral
Hearing. On 16 May 1994 the Stock Exchange informed the Authority that the
rules on minimum commissions would be abolished with effect from 17 May 1994.
On 27 May 1994 the Stock Exchange informed the Authority that it was
withdrawing its request for an Oral Hearing having decided not to contest the
Authority's objections in respect of the agency rule. It subsequently
announced its intention to change this rule, subject to the approval of the
Minister for Finance.
The
Facts
(a) The
Subject of the Notification
2. The
notification relates to the rules of the Irish Stock Exchange in relation to
dealings in Irish Government Securities (Gilts) by member firms dated January
1987. The rules set out the basis on which member firms of the Exchange may
deal in Irish Gilts. In particular they provide that brokers may operate in an
agency capacity only and prohibit brokers from competing on the basis of
commission levels by setting out fixed commissions to be charged by all member
firms in respect of gilts with over five years to maturity. The rate of
commission has been approved by the Minister for Finance.
(b) The
Parties
3. The
parties involved in the arrangements are the Irish Stock Exchange and its
member firms. The Irish Stock Exchange is presently constituted as an
administrative unit, being in effect the Irish branch of the International
Stock Exchange of the United Kingdom and the Republic of Ireland Ltd., which is
owned by its member firms throughout Ireland and the UK. Its functions include
the regulation of its member firms. There are currently 12 member firms of the
Irish Stock Exchange and they are listed in Annex 1.
[1]
The Authority is aware that there are proposals to establish the Irish Stock
Exchange as a separate entity independent of the UK Stock Exchange.
4. The
Stock Exchange has submitted that none of these firms has a shareholding in any
of the other firms listed or any right to control, manage or influence the
board or partnership of another. Some of the stockbroking firms are however,
subsidiaries of, or partly owned by, other companies.
5. Stockbroking
firms act as intermediaries in the gilt and equity markets. They are also
engaged in a number of other activities including
inter
alia
the provision of advice to investment clients and the organising of share
placings for corporate clients.
(c) The
Product and the Market
6. A
gilt is an Irish Government security. The Government issues or sells gilts in
order to fund its borrowing requirements. Gilts generally offer a fixed rate
of interest for a number of years and have a specific redemption date. Such
gilts are usually bought by institutional investors such as insurance
companies, pension funds and banks. Private investors account for an almost
negligible part of gilt sales.
7. Gilts
were traditionally issued by the Department of Finance although this role has
now been assumed by the National Treasury Management Agency (NTMA). The NTMA
creates new stocks with a particular maturity date and coupon from time to
time. They might issue only a relatively small amount initially but further
amounts may be issued or ´tranched' as the need for funds and the market
demand for stock allows. Tranches of existing stocks may also be created.
8. As
an inducement to investors to hold gilts the Department of Finance undertook to
buy back stock at a price set from time to time. Increased budget deficits
from the mid 1970s onwards led to a substantial increase in the amount of
Government gilts held by institutions. In addition as investors became more
willing to trade their gilt portfolios opportunities for brokers arose to find
sellers and buyers of gilts. This resulted in the development of a secondary
market for gilts. Gilts are bought and sold by investors on the secondary
market between their issue and redemption date. Most transactions on the
secondary market are arranged by stockbroking firms with the vast majority of
transactions conducted by telephone. Secondary market trading now dominates
overall turnover so that the Department of Finance's role as a market maker
diminished over time. The relevant market is the secondary gilt market. The
relevant geographical market is the State.
9. The
total value of Government stock or gilts outstanding at the end of 1993 was
over £14bn. (See Table 1). The main holders of gilts are financial
institutions. These can be divided into two broad classes. Banks and building
societies tend to hold gilts for investment purposes on their own account and
also, in the former case, to comply with liquidity ratio requirements imposed
by the Central Bank of Ireland. Such institutions tend mainly to hold short
dated gilts. Life assurance and pension funds effectively invest in gilts on
behalf of their policyholders and would largely invest in medium and long dated
gilts. The tendency for the different institutions to operate largely in
different areas of the market reflects the differing maturity ranges of their
respective liabilities. Insurance companies were the largest domestic holders
of gilts accounting almost 29% of stock outstanding. The personal and
corporate sectors hold a very small proportion of outstanding gilts. In effect
the personal sector is a major holder of gilts indirectly through life
assurance and pension policies.
10. In
recent years overseas institutions, particularly German institutions, have
become major holders of gilts. At the end of 1991 non-resident gilt holdings
accounted for almost 30% of stock outstanding. This fell sharply during 1992,
due largely to the currency crisis. By the end of 1993 non resident holdings
of gilts was more than £4bn, just £120m below the end 1991 level,
representing almost 29% of gilts outstanding.
Table
1: Government Stock - Nominal Holdings £M
1993
1992
Government
Departments
262.9
( 1.9)
441.6 ( 3.3)
Central
Bank
180.0
( 1.3)
240.0 ( 1.8)
Associated
Banks
2157.3 ( 15.3)
2049.6 ( 15.5)
Non-Associated
Banks
625.7
( 4.4)
1023.1 ( 7.7)
Building
Societies
427.4
( 3.0)
838.1 ( 6.3)
Insurance
Companies
4035.9 ( 28.5)
3702.8 ( 27.9)
Pension
Funds
1115.0 ( 7.9)
1139.5 ( 8.6)
Unit
and Investment Trusts
306.5
( 2.2)
288.1 ( 2.2)
Commercial
Companies
299.6
( 2.1)
375.0 ( 2.8)
Personal
Sector
359.7
( 2.5)
447.7 ( 3.4)
Other
327.1
( 2.3)
387.1 ( 2.9)
Non-Resident
Holdings
4047.3 ( 28.6) 2320.7 ( 17.5)
Total
14144.4 (100.0) 13253.3 (100.0)
Figures
in parentheses are percentage shares.
Source:
Central Bank; Quarterly Bulletin, Summer 1994, Table D2.
11. Gilts
may be divided into three broad categories according to their maturity date.
Those maturing in less than 5 years would be described as shorts, those with a
maturity date of between 5 to 15 years are mediums, while those with a maturity
of over 15 years are long gilts. At end 1992 there were a total of 31 stock
issues.
[2]
Table 2 illustrates that 45% of the gilts outstanding are shorts. This
proportion has fallen in recent years.
Table
2: Maturity Range of Gilts
(%
distribution)
1991 1992
1993
Stocks
due to mature in
less
than 5 years
51.7 50.0 45.4
5-15
years
39.8 40.5 45.8
15
years or more
8.4
9.6
8.8
Source:
Central Bank Quarterly Bulletin Summer 1994, Table D2.
12. Stockbroking
firms are engaged
inter
alia
in arranging the purchase and sale of gilts on behalf of investors on the
secondary market. These firms are only allowed by the Stock Exchange to act in
an agency capacity and must have on their staff individuals licensed by the
Minister for Finance to deal in gilts for commission.
Table
3: Gilt Market Turnover £M.
Under
5 Years
Over
5 Years
Total
to
Maturity
to Maturity
1990 28180
7917
36097
1991 17026 18456 35482
1992 21093 26809 47902
1993 30281 36107 66388
Source:
Central Bank Quarterly Bulletin Summer 1994, Table C20.
13. Total
turnover has increased sharply since 1991. Apart from 1990 more than half of
total turnover involved stock with more than five years to maturity. There
were over 19,000 bargains involving gilts with more than five years to maturity
in 1993, 55% of all gilt bargains. The Irish Times reported that total gilt
commissions paid to stockbrokers in 1993 by Irish institutions alone amounted
to £4.5m. This was 22% up on the 1992 total.
14. The
market is in fact a highly concentrated one with just four firms accounting for
the bulk of gilt market transactions According to a report in the Irish Times,
Davy Stockbrokers accounted for almost 31% of gilt market transactions, while
the top four firms accounted for almost 90% of the market. (See Table 4). In
effect many of the smaller stockbroking firms are not heavily involved in the
gilt market, with most of their business being accounted for by private
clients. During 1993 two smaller firms have managed to secure a significant
increase in their market share. In one case they did so, according to
newspaper reports, by offering a partial rebate of commissions to institutions
if and when the current scale of fixed commissions is revised.
Table
4: Gilt Commissions Paid to Stockbrokers
1991
1992
1993
%
£m
%
£m
%
Davy
Stockbrokers
29.3
1.19 (32.3) 1.45
(31.0)
Goodbody 21.4 0.79 (21.2) 0.90
(20.0)
NCB 21.6 0.86 (23.1) 0.86 (19.0)
Riada 20.8 0.61 (16.6) 0.81 (18.0)
Bloxham
-
-
0.23 (
5.0)
MMI
-
-
0.23
(
5.0)
Others
6.9 0.25
(6.7)
0.09 (
2.0)
Note:
Separate figures for Bloxham and MMI were not published for 1991 and 1992 and
they are included in the total for others.
Source:
Irish Times 7 April 1993 and 17 February 1994.
(d) The
Arrangements
15. The
notified arrangements involved the Stock Exchange Rules as they applied to
transactions in Government gilts. They provided that stockbrokers may only act
in an agency capacity in respect of Irish Government securities and were
obliged to charge a fixed rate of commission on transactions in gilts with more
than five years to maturity. These conditions were set out in the ´Rules
and Regulations of the Irish Stock Exchange'. The relevant rules are set out
below.
49.1 ´A
Member firm shall only deal as an agent in respect of any security issued or
guaranteed by the Government of the Republic of Ireland.'
75.1 (1)
´The Rules and Regulations of the Stock Exchange relating to Commission
shall apply in toto on bargains on Securities issued or guaranteed by the
Government of the Republic of Ireland, a broker who is subject to the
jurisdiction of the Republic of Ireland shall charge his client Commission at
not less than the rates laid down in Appendix II to these unit rules and no
reduction thereof may be allowed except as authorised by the provisions of the
Rules and Regulations of The Stock Exchange.'
77.1 ´A
broking firm shall charge commission in respect of every bargain made on a
client's behalf and in respect of every service for which a charge is
prescribed.'
78.1 ´In
the case of securities issued by the Government of Ireland, the commission
chargeable by a Broking Firm shall be at not less than the rates adopted by the
Irish Administrative Unit and set out in Appendix II - Irish Government Funds
of these rules, except to the extent authorised by these Rules.'
16. Rule
79.1 and 2 provides for lower, albeit fixed rates of commission to be applied
in respect of a new security issue with a maturity date of more than ten years
on transactions effected within three months of the first day of dealings done
for the same principal in such a new issue. Rule 80 allows brokers to waive
commissions in certain limited circumstances. Rule 81 allows for certain
reductions in the case of a change from one security to another for the same
principal.
17. Details
of the rates of commission specified in Appendix II of the Stock Exchange Rules
are set out in Table 5 below.
Table
5: Scale of Minimum Commissions
(for
Irish Government Funds.)
0.52% on the first £2500 consideration
0.1625% on the next £15500 consideration
0.0813% on the next £232000 consideration
0.065% on the next £750000 consideration
0.0585% on the next £3000000 consideration
0.026% on the next £6000000 consideration
0.013% on the excess.
18. The
Irish Times reported on 7 November 1992 that one of the smaller stockbroking
firms, MMI, had announced plans to offer discounts of up to 20 percent on gilt
deals. MMI was formed early in 1992 when MMI moneybrokers acquired Doak &
Company a small stockbroking firm. The Stock Exchange reportedly objected to
the MMI proposal to charge less than the minimum commissions set in its rules.
The Irish Times report also claimed that a Japanese broking house had decided
to make a market in Irish gilts from its London trading room although it
appears that they subsequently withdrew from the market.
(e) Submissions
of the Parties
19. The
Irish Stock Exchange has argued that the arrangements do not have as their
object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition in
trade in any goods or services in the State or in any part of the State within
the meaning of section 4(1) of the Competition Act. They have argued that
fixed commissions are required because banks who are large holders and traders
of gilts may also be owners or controllers of broking operations. Without
fixed commissions they could obtain the services of a subsidiary broker at a
nominal charge. Other buyers of gilts would recognise this possibility and
would treat brokers as principals quickly leading to a situation where the
major participants in the market were principal traders and there would emerge
a market making system. The Exchange argued that this would reduce liquidity
and turnover in the market and raise costs. The Stock Exchange also argued
that a ´standard' rate of commission would emerge even in the absence of
fixed commission arrangements, given the nature of the market involved. Thus
they submitted that the arrangement merely formalised the structure that would
emerge under a negotiated commission regime, except that it preserved the
agency broking structure of the market, thus ensuring the transparency of every
trade.
20. It
was claimed that the agency broking system benefited investors and Government
through improved liquidity and lower overall dealing costs. It was argued that
the commission levels prevailing resulted in bid-offer spreads which were quite
narrow. The parties stated that: ´A reduction of commission levels, if it
reduced competition in the broking market, would be offset many times by wider
spreads.' They also stated that any restrictions were greatly ameliorated by
the freedom of investors to deal direct without the use of brokers, by the
existence of alternatives to the gilt market (i.e. futures), by the freedom of
entry into broking and by the requirement that the commission rates be approved
by the Department of Finance.
21. The
Exchange also argued that, even if the fixed commission rules could be
considered to offend against section 4(1), a licence was justified. It was
stated that the primary objective of the fixed commission rules was to
implement the provisions relating to the licence to deal in Government
securities on a commission basis which must be obtained from the Minister for
Finance. The Exchange submitted that brokers had contributed to the
development of the secondary trading in gilts and an increase in the liquidity
of the market. It indicated that without fixed commissions it would be
impossible to distinguish between an agency transaction and a principal
transaction and that this would lead to a deterioration in the quality of the
market. It was claimed that this would cause a significant number of
investors, especially overseas investors, to cease to trade. Competitive
broking would therefore disappear.
22. The
Stock Exchange argued that the elimination of fixed commissions would cause the
market to evolve fairly quickly into one of competing market-makers. They
claimed, however, that there were only two or three domestic banking groups
with the high level of capital required for adequate market-making and that it
was therefore unlikely that a competitive market making system could be put in
place. They also submitted that to increase the number of competitive market
makers it would be necessary to attract foreign houses, ´so transferring
employment and value added abroad.'
23. The
Exchange argued that broking was essential to the maintenance of market
liquidity. They also submitted that any change to the system could damage
market confidence which would be difficult to re-establish. They stated that
domestic market participants did not consider that gilt commissions were a
particularly important factor. They went on to state that:
´The
abolition of fixed commission rates would lead rapidly to a fundamental change
in the structure of the gilt market and would lead to a less competitive, less
liquid market dominated by larger financial institutions whose market making
capacity would have to be supported by the Authorities.
We
believe there is a grave danger that in the absence of agency broking - which
would disappear without a minimum commission regime - the liquidity of the
market would dwindle and its continuing attraction to foreign investors would
be greatly reduced.
The
reduction in liquidity would be reflected in wider spreads which would far
outweigh any potential savings in commission levels currently required by the
voluntary use of an agency broker.'
24. In
support of its request the Stock Exchange submitted a simulation exercise on
Market Making on Long Bonds prepared by Mr. Barry Dillon of Davy Stockbrokers.
This claimed that market making would require relatively wide spreads thereby
reducing liquidity in the market. A separate study entitled The Development of
the Irish Bond Market prepared by Mr. Jim O'Leary and Mr. Tony Garry, also of
Davy Stockbrokers concluded that while spreads on Irish long gilts appeared
relatively high, this was attributable to a number of factors including
inter
alia
the size of the market and the degree of stock dispersion. It rejected
arguments that the replacement of the present agency broking system with a
market making system would have a positive effect on market liquidity.
(f) Legislation.
25. The
Act for the Better Regulation of Stock Brokers 1799 provides
inter
alia
that any licensed stockbroker shall not buy or sell Government stocks or
securities on his own account when employed by any person not being a broker.
In 1918 the Stockbrokers (Ireland) Act was enacted which provided that the
Dublin Stock Exchange could set maximum rates of fees which may be charged by a
licensed stockbroker in Ireland on the sale or purchase of any Government stock
or securities, subject to the approval of the Lord Lieutenant. Responsibility
for approving such rates now lies with the Minister for Finance.
(g) Views
of Third Parties.
National
Treasury Management Agency
26. Under
the
National Treasury Management Agency Act, 1990 the NTMA is responsible for
the management of the national debt, a function previously discharged by the
Department of Finance. The NTMA has effectively assumed the Department's role
of financing maturing debt and the Exchequer Borrowing Requirement (EBR)
through the issue and sale of new gilts. In addition the NTMA is also engaged
in actively promoting depth and liquidity in the gilt market through active
intervention in the secondary market. This latter function is in contrast with
the approach adopted by the Department in the past when the development of the
secondary market was due purely to the activities of stockbrokers. The NTMA in
its submission to the Authority stated that it had ´a vital and unique
interest in any matter relating to Government securities, including the rules
of the Irish Stock Exchange pertaining to those securities.'
27. The
NTMA went on to state that:
´In
the Agency's view the minimum fixed rate commission arrangement is not
necessary for the proper functioning of the gilt market. Moreover, the
arrangement does not allow of a competitive broking system in as much as all
investors, regardless of size, are obliged to pay the same price irrespective
of the level or quality of service. The Agency does not accept the Stock
Exchange's assertion that the deregulation of commission rates would
necessarily lead to a fundamental change in the structure of the market, in the
form of market making, and to reduced liquidity.'
It
noted that equity market transactions continue to be conducted on an
agency-only broker basis although negotiable commissions have applied since
1986. It then stated that:
´In
any event, even if some form of market making were to be introduced in the gilt
market following the abolition of fixed rate commissions, such a development,
which would be in line with practice in most other European markets, would be
welcomed in principle by the Agency.'
28. The
NTMA also argued that, while it was true that buyers and sellers of gilts were
free to deal directly with one another and avoid paying commissions, the
Exchange had the unique characteristics of prudential regulation and investor
protection, so that the vast bulk of investors did not deal outside of it,
giving brokers a
de
facto
monopoly. It pointed out that institutions who were actually managing funds on
behalf of individual and corporate investors were under an obligation to those
investors to deal at the best price. By not dealing through the market they
would be exposed to claims that they had not done so. The NTMA also indicated
that the Stock Exchange simulation, showing that market making in long gilts
would reduce liquidity, was seriously flawed.
Irish
Association of Investment Managers
29. The
Irish Association of Investment Managers (IAIM) represents institutional
investors in the Irish market. IAIM indicated that it had 18 corporate members
who between them held 35-40% of the total Irish gilt market with a considerably
higher share of the medium and long end of the market to which fixed commission
rates apply. They claimed that IAIM members had paid £4.5m in commission
on gilt transactions to Irish brokers in 1993.
30. IAIM
stated that it was opposed to the Stock Exchange's application for a
certificate on the basis that the system of fixed gilt commissions contravened
section 4 of the Competition Act. It was also opposed to the Exchange's
application for a licence as it believed that this would institutionalise an
anti-competitive practice which was not in the interests of the market and was
unnecessary for the maintenance of an agency broking system.
31. IAIM
submitted that commission rates were payable to agency brokers for their
services as intermediaries. Commission rates include payment for the basic
service of matching buyers and sellers and any added value provided by the
broker over and above that basic role. The latter includes the provision of
research, advice, ability to deal in size, knowledge of international markets
etc. These demand a higher payment than would be the case for the basic
service. They argued that fixed commissions incorporated payments for a
composite service and that it was anti-competitive as it prevented new or
existing brokers from offering a mix of one or more these services to clients
at appropriate commissions. It forced investors to buy a composite service and
meant that brokers competed only on the basis of services offered, rather than
on the basis of price and/or services offered.
32. IAIM
argued that an efficient market was not characterised by the existence of fixed
commissions and that it could be argued that, with negotiable commissions,
turnover and consequently liquidity would be increased. In addition they
submitted that the abolition of fixed commissions would not have the effect
claimed by the Stock Exchange. Specifically IAIM indicated that the move to a
market making system was not an inevitable result of the abolition of fixed
commissions. They noted that the abolition of fixed commissions for equities
had not resulted in a move to dual capacity. Similarly they argued that the
Exchange's claim that certain banks would use their position as owners or
controllers of certain broking firms to obtain their services at nominal
charges, thus leading to market making was not sustainable. In support of this
argument they pointed out that banks were the most active players in the short
end of the market where commissions are negotiable and their involvement has
not affected broking in shorts. In addition it was claimed that, if such
practices were to occur, the banks would realise that other investors would not
deal with the broker concerned, thus undermining its viability. They also
claimed that banks with broking subsidiaries should be indifferent to
commission levels as they were simply a transfer from one area of operations to
another.
33. In
conclusion IAIM argued that the introduction of market making was not related
to the issue of fixed commissions. They did not accept the claim that the
possibility of principals dealing directly outside the Exchange ensured that
brokers did not have a monopoly. However, they considered that the emergence
of overseas brokers willing to compete on price and not bound by minimum
commission rules had the potential to break the stockbroking monopoly.
Other
Submissions
34. A
Mr. Frank Kelleher complained that the system of fixed commissions was
anti-competitive and that the granting of a licence for such a practice would
not be in the interests of the country. Mr. Kelleher indicated that he was
currently involved in a venture that proposed to set up a technology driven
trading organisation in Dublin and that the Stock Exchange had indicated that
any attempt by an organisation to undercut the minimum commission rates would
result in its membership being revoked. He claimed that as his organisation
aimed to undercut the current minimum level of commissions in order to attract
clients, it was unlikely that the Exchange authorities would recommend that his
organisation be granted membership, if and when, sought.
(h) UK
Experience.
35. As
pointed out above the Irish Stock Exchange is an administrative unit of the
International Stock Exchange of the United Kingdom and Ireland. Prior to
October 1986, the UK Stock Exchange also required UK stockbrokers to charge
minimum fixed commissions. On 9 February 1979 the UK Director General of Fair
Trading referred the Stock Exchange rules to the UK Restrictive Practices
Court. Among the main anti-competitive restrictions cited by the Director
General in announcing the reference was the provision preventing stockbrokers
from providing services below specified minimum rates of commission. The
reference also cited certain other restrictions such as the provision that
jobbers could not act as brokers and the requirement for all deals to be put
through a jobber.
36. On
27 July 1983 the UK Secretary of State for Trade and Industry announced that
the Stock Exchange was to amend its rules. In particular it proposed to
dismantle in stages the rules which prescribed minimum scales of commission,
with this process to be completed by 31 December 1986. As a result the
Government amended the UK Restrictive Practices Act to exclude the rules of the
Stock Exchange from its provisions. In fact the move from minimum to
negotiated commissions was completed on 27 October 1986. At that time minimum
commissions for both equities and short gilts were also abolished in Ireland.
The Minister for Finance announced, however, that such commissions would be
retained in Ireland in the case of dealings in medium and long term government
gilts, although the rate of commission was reduced considerably.
(h) Subsequent
developments.
37. In
a report in the Irish Times on 3 January 1994, it was stated that the NTMA were
anxious to see a change in the operation of the gilt market. In particular the
NTMA was reported to be seeking a move to a ´market-making' system in
gilts. Mr. John Corrigan of the NTMA was reported as expressing the view that
such a system would improve liquidity in the market and would thereby lower the
gap between Irish and German bond yields. A report in the Sunday Business Post
of 6 February again indicated that the NTMA were anxious to see a change to a
market making system. According to the report the IAIM were opposed to such a
change.
38. On
10 March 1994 the Authority issued a Statement of Objections to the Stock
Exchange indicating that it intended to refuse to issue a certificate or grant
a licence in respect of the notified arrangements. In particular the Authority
stated that, in its opinion, the rules setting minimum commissions for gilt
transactions and requiring that brokers act only as agents in respect of such
transactions were anti-competitive and offended against
section 4(1) of the
Competition Act. It also indicated that, in its view, none of these rules
satisfied the requirements for a licence set out in
section 4(2) of
the Act.
On 6 April 1994 the Stock Exchange indicated that it had decided not to
challenge the Authority's objections to the fixed commission regime. It
indicated that it did not accept the Authority's views on the agency rule and
requested an Oral Hearing. On 16 May 1994 the Stock Exchange informed the
Authority that the rules on minimum commissions would be abolished with effect
from 17 May 1994. A report in the Sunday Business Post on 29 May 1994
indicated that gilt commissions had fallen significantly as a result of the
abolition of minimum commissions and the introduction of negotiated commissions
for all gilt transactions. On 27 May 1994 the Stock Exchange informed the
Authority that it was withdrawing its request for an Oral Hearing having
decided not to contest the Authority's objections in respect of the agency
rule. It subsequently announced its intention to change this rule, subject to
the approval of the Minister for Finance. The IAIM wrote requesting that the
Authority indicate in its decision whether the arrangements which IAIM would
like to see introduced in place of the agent only rule would meet the
requirements for a certificate or licence.
Assessment
(a) Section
4(1)
39.
Section
4(1) of the Competition Act states that ´all agreements between
undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices
which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion
of competition in trade in any goods or services in the State or in any part of
the State are prohibited and void.'
(b) The
Parties
40. The
notified arrangements involve certain rules of the Irish Stock Exchange. The
Irish Stock Exchange is constituted as an administrative unit of the
International Stock Exchange of the United Kingdom and the Republic of Ireland
Ltd. It is owned by its members which are stockbroking firms.
Section 3(1) of
the Act defines an undertaking as ´a person being an individual, a body
corporate or an unincorporated body of persons engaged for gain in the
production, supply or distribution of goods or the provision of a service.'
Stockbroking firms are engaged in the provision of services for gain.
Consequently the Irish Stock Exchange is an association of undertakings within
the meaning of
section 4(1), as its members are undertakings. This view is
supported by EC law, as Bellamy and Child point out:
´Although
trade associations of various kinds are the commonest ´associations of
undertakings' the word ´associations' is not limited to any particular
type of association. It includes agricultural co-operatives, associations
without legal personality, non-profit making associations, associations of
associations and an association outside the Community.
[3]'
The
legal form of the association has been found to be irrelevant.
[4]
(c) The
Arrangements
41. The
notified arrangements involved the Stock Exchange Rules as they apply to
transactions in Government gilts. They provided that stockbrokers may only act
in an agency capacity in respect of Irish Government securities and must charge
a fixed rate of commission on transactions in medium and long gilts. These
conditions were set out in the ´Rules and Regulations of the Irish Stock
Exchange'. The Rules constituted a decision by an association of undertakings.
This view is also supported by EC precedents.
´The
concept of ´decision' includes the rules of the association in question,
decisions binding upon the members and recommendations. Agreements implemented
within the framework of the association concerned may be analysed either as
´decisions' of that association or ´agreements' between the members.'
[5]The
Rules of the Exchange and the Rules relating to minimum commissions also
constitute an agreement between undertakings since they were agreed by the
Member Firms which, as already pointed out, are undertakings. Each of the
relevant rules is now considered.
(d) Applicability
of section 4(1).
(i) Minimum
Commissions
42. Rules
75.1(1) and 78.1 provided that brokers must charge no less than the rates
adopted by the Irish Administrative Unit and set out in Appendix II of the
Rules. Lower rates were permitted under the Rules in certain limited
circumstances. The requirement in both of these Rules that brokers should not
charge less than the rate of commission fixed by the Irish Exchange on
transactions in Irish Government Gilts prevented price competition between
stockbrokers in respect of such transactions. The vast majority of
transactions in Irish Government Gilts were conducted using stockbrokers.
43. Theoretically
it might have been possible for principals to by-pass brokers and deal directly
with one another. The notifying parties in this instance had sought to argue
that the arrangements were not anti-competitive as investors did not have to
deal through brokers. It was argued in other submissions that this is not a
practical alternative for a number of reasons. Clearly if institutions
by-passed brokers they could avoid paying commission altogether. The fact that
the overwhelming majority of transactions are conducted through brokers implies
that direct dealing is not a viable alternative. Similarly while transactions
could also be channelled through the futures exchange, the fact that there is
so little activity in that market again suggests that it is not a viable
alternative. It is clear, therefore, that such alternatives do not represent a
realistic alternative to brokers and that brokers did not have to depart from
the fixed commissions as a result of competition from such alternatives.
44. It
was pointed out above that transactions in short dated gilts were not subject
to fixed commissions. The Authority believes that short dated gilts are not
sufficiently close substitutes for mediums and longs to be regarded as part of
the same market. Consequently it does not believe that the absence of fixed
minimum commissions on short gilts means that their application to mediums and
longs did not amount to a restriction of competition. Quite simply the Stock
Exchange could not discriminate in this fashion between the commission rules
applying to the different types of gilts if they were in fact substitutes for
one another. The rule prescribing fixed minimum commissions to be charged by
brokers on transactions in Irish Government Gilts prevented brokers from
competing on price, and this amounted to a restriction of competition within
the State.
45. Price
fixing agreements have been consistently regarded as in breach of Article 85(1)
of the Treaty of Rome. Bellamy and Child point out that:
´Since
price is the main instrument of competition, Article 85(1)(a) expressly
prohibits agreements, which "directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling
prices or any other trading conditions." An agreement to fix prices by its
very nature constitutes a restriction on competition within the meaning of
Article 85(1).'
[6]
46. They
go on to state that:
´Article
85(1) is infringed by an explicit agreement between suppliers to fix prices,
and also by a concerted practice to restrict price competition, for example
informal concertation on the dates and amounts of price increases or the
exchange of price information. Similarly the prohibition of Article 85(1)
covers not only "prices" in the narrow sense but also discounts, margins,
rebates and credit terms.'
[7]
47. Van
Bael and Bellis point out that:
´Although
there exist no
per
se
rules in EEC competition law, horizontal price fixing arrangements have always
been held incompatible with Article 85(1) and have generally been denied an
exemption'.
[8]In
the US horizontal price fixing agreements have generally been regarded by the
courts as a
per
se
violation of the antitrust statutes.
48. In
a number decisions relating to the rules and regulations of a number of the
London Futures Exchanges, the EU Commission decided that rules, which set
minimum net rates of commission to be charged by members, infringed Article
85(1). In the London Sugar Futures Market case, for example, the Commission
stated that:
´The
Rules and Regulations as originally notified specified the minimum net rates of
commission which could be charged by a member. The Committee had powers to
suspend or expel offending members. The minimum commission rates varied
according to who was paying and who was receiving the commission..........The
Commission considered the above described system of specified minimum
commission rates as a form of price-fixing that violated Article 85(1) of the
EEC Treaty. The LSFM was requested to abandon the system of fixed minimum
rates. The system has now been abolished as such. References to the system in
the Rules and Regulations have been deleted. The rules now provide that
business concluded on the floor of the market between Full Members may be
transacted free of commission. Commission must be charged on all other
transactions between members and non-members. The Commission believes that
this obligation is not appreciably restrictive of competition because it only
entails the obligation to charge ´a' commission without any reference to
the rate. It follows that complete freedom exists to negotiate the commission
rates.'
[9]The
Commission took an identical view in a number of other cases where negative
clearances were granted after the provisions specifying minimum rates of
commission were dropped.
1[0]
49. There
are also a number of Commission decisions and judgments of the European Court
of Justice in other cases which found that price-fixing agreements infringed
Article 85(1) and which are relevant to the present notification. In IFTRA
1[1]
the EC Commission found that an agreement between producers of virgin aluminium
not to sell below their published prices was in breach of Article 85(1). The
Commission found that the arrangements ´provide the parties with means of
shelter from competition to the extent that price stability is increased and
that the parties are enabled to predict each other's price policy with a
reasonable degree of certainty.
1[2]'
It
went on to state that:
´..every
producer should have complete discretion to establish his own policy in these
matters without risking the accusation that he is violating the spirit of an
agreement. The contractual organisation of a system requiring adherence to
various existing prices and whereby price stability is encouraged by the
recommendations which are made to the parties to use and adhere to price
lists.....constitutes a major restriction of competition, both in its object
and its effect.'
1[3]
50. In
Cementhandelaren the European Court of Justice ruled that:
´The
fixing of a price, even one which merely constitutes a target, affects
competition, because it enables all the participants to predict with a
reasonable degree of certainty what the pricing policy pursued by their
competitors will be.'
1[4]
51. In
the present context it is also relevant that the European Court of Justice has
ruled that:
´A
recommendation of an association of undertakings, even if it has no binding
effect, cannot escape that article [85(1)] where compliance with the
recommendations by the undertakings to which it is addressed has an appreciable
influence on competition in the market in question.'
1[5]It
is clear, however, that the rules of the Stock Exchange go beyond being mere
recommendations. As pointed out above when one of the smaller stockbroking
firms attempted to offer lower commissions on gilts to clients, the Exchange
threatened to expel it. The use or threatened use of sanctions to ensure
compliance with the system of fixed minimum commissions supports the view that
they are anti-competitive.
52. The
Stock Exchange argued that a ´standard' rate of commission would emerge
even in the absence of fixed commission arrangements, given the nature of the
market involved. Thus they submitted that the arrangement merely formalised
the structure that would emerge under a negotiated commission regime, except
that it preserved the agency broking structure of the market, thus ensuring the
transparency of every trade. The Authority rejects this argument. It is true
that in the absence of fixed minimum commissions a uniform rate of commission
might emerge as a result of competition. In a truly competitive market
homogeneous products would tend to sell at a uniform price. There is, however,
a fundamental difference between a price which is set by competitive market
forces and one which is based upon an agreement between competitors or upon the
rule of an association.
53. The
Authority also wishes to point out that, in its view, price fixing is
anti-competitive regardless of the level at which prices may be fixed. It has
long been recognised under US competition law, for example, that price fixing
arrangements cannot be justified on the basis that the prices set were
´reasonable'. Thus, for example in Trenton Potteries
1[6]
Mr. Justice Stone noted that:
´The
aim and result of every price-fixing agreement, if effective, is the
elimination of one form of competition. The power to fix prices, whether
reasonably exercised or not, involves power to control the market and to fix
arbitrary and unreasonable prices. The reasonable price fixed today may
through economic and business changes become the unreasonable price of tomorrow.'
A
similar view was taken in Socony Vacuum Oil
1[7]
where the Supreme Court's judgment, as delivered by Mr. Justice Douglas
outlining why the reasonableness of prices could not serve to justify
price-fixing stated:
´The
reasonableness of prices has no constancy due to the dynamic quality of
business facts underlying price structures. Those who fixed reasonable prices
today would perpetuate unreasonable prices tomorrow, since those prices would
not be subject to continuous administrative supervision and readjustment in
light of changed conditions.'
54. The
Stock Exchange argued that the abolition of fixed commissions would lead to the
breakdown of the agency broking system and the present arrangements would be
replaced by a system of competing market makers. They submitted that this
would reduce liquidity and turnover in the market and raise costs. The claim
that the abolition of fixed minimum commissions would lead to the end of an
agency broking system was disputed by both the IAIM and the NTMA.
Section 4(1)
of
the Act prohibits anti-competitive agreements. It is designed to protect
competition not competitors. The Authority in considering whether an
arrangement offends against
section 4(1) is required to decide whether or not
it prevents, restricts or distorts competition. It may be that the removal of
anti-competitive arrangements will result in a market structure very different
to that which exists under such arrangements. In particular it may well change
the nature of the entities operating in the market. It is not, however, for
the Authority to express a preference for one type of system over another.
Rather it must decide whether a particular arrangement is or is not
anti-competitive.
55. The
Authority is not convinced that the abolition of fixed commissions would lead
inevitably to a move to a system of market makers. In taking this view it
notes the views expressed by the IAIM and the NTMA. It also notes that the
absence of fixed minimum commissions in the equity market and in the case of
short dated gilts has not resulted in a move to market making. It is also
relevant that attempts to offer discounts on gilts have been made by one of the
smaller broking firms which would be unlikely to have the resources necessary
to engage in market making.
56. The
Stock Exchange also argued that the restrictions in respect of commissions did
not restrict competition as brokers competed in other ways such as quality of
service provided to clients. Many brokers provide a wide range of back-up
services to their clients including detailed economic analysis and advice.
Such services are financed out of commission income. While minimum commissions
financed such services, they meant that investors are prevented from deciding
which services they want. Many of the larger institutional investors have the
resources to carry out their own detailed research and do so. Yet they were
obliged, under the notified arrangements, to pay for such services which they
might not want.
57. The
Exchange did not argue that the commission arrangements were designed to
prevent free riding although there may be some scope for this. For example, if
commissions varied depending on the level of back-up services offered by
brokers, then investors could obtain detailed analysis and advice from the
broker providing such services, but then deal through a broker charging a lower
commission and not providing such services. There appears to be no reason why
brokers offering detailed research and analysis to their clients could not
specifically charge for such services thereby avoiding the free rider problem.
Indeed it is possible that if cross subsidisation of such services were
eliminated a situation might arise whereby specialist firms decided to offer
such services to meet the demands of gilt market investors.
58. In
sum therefore the Authority believes that the setting of fixed minimum
commissions by the Stock Exchange for transactions in Irish Government
securities, which had to be adhered to by all member firms, eliminated the
possibility for stockbrokers to compete on price in the secondary market for
such securities. In the Authority's opinion the elimination of price
competition in this way prevents competition in the relevant market.
Agreements to fix selling prices are listed as a specific example of the type
of agreement prohibited by
section 4(1) of
the Act. Consequently in the
Authority's opinion the rule requiring Stock Exchange members to charge minimum
rates of commission on Irish Government securities offended against
section 4(1).
59. Rule
79.1 and 2 provided for lower, albeit fixed rates of commission to be applied
in respect of a new security issue with a maturity date of more than ten years
on transactions effected within three months of the first day of dealings done
for the same principal in such a new issue. Again, in the Authority's opinion
this rule offended against
section 4(1) since it fixed a minimum rate of
commission to be charged on such transactions. The fact that this was lower
than the normal rates applied under Rule 78.1 is irrelevant for the purpose of
determining whether or not it offends against
section 4(1).
60. Rule
81 allowed for certain reductions in the case of a change from one security to
another for the same principal. Again, however, as this specified the
reductions which may be offered from the standard rates it also offended
against
section 4(1).
61. The
1918 Stockbrokers (Ireland) Act provides for the setting by the Stock Exchange
of a maximum rate of fees which may be charged by licensed stockbrokers on
gilts. The Rules which were considered in the preceding paras relate to the
fixing of minimum rates of commission. The Authority does not believe that the
fixing of minimum commission rates was permitted by that Act thereby excluding
such a practice from the scope of
section 4(1) of the Competition Act.
(ii) The
Agent Only Rule.
62. Rule
49.1 provides that Stock Exchange member firms could only deal as an agent in
respect of any security issued or guaranteed by the Government of the Republic
of Ireland. If this restriction were removed certain types of institutions
which currently operate as principals might be interested in offering broking
services. In reality a number of large financial institutions have
stockbroking firms as wholly owned subsidiaries and there appears to be nothing
to stop any institution setting up its own broking subsidiary or acquiring one.
Consequently the restriction would not appear to have the effect of preventing
new entrants from coming into the market for stockbroking services.
63. The
Authority must also consider whether the restriction on brokers acting as
principals prevents, restricts or distorts competition in the gilt market
itself. The Authority has accepted the view that the abolition of fixed
commissions will not automatically lead to a system of market making and that
in such circumstances brokers may continue to operate in an agency only
capacity. Indeed they would be required to do so if Rule 49.1 remained.
Clearly this rule prevented brokers from operating as buyers and sellers of
gilts in the gilt market The rule requiring brokers to act only as agents
prevented them operating as market makers should they wish to, and indeed
appeared to prevent any other entity from operating as a market maker, since
such an entity would in effect be operating outside of the market. In the
absence of such a restriction some broking firms could conceivably decide to
operate as market makers. This would obviously have some impact on competition
in the gilt market itself.
64. The
Authority accepts that the establishment of a market making operation would
require a considerable capital investment and that this would appear to be
beyond the existing resources of most brokers. Thus it may be that only a
small number of brokers might establish themselves as market makers, while the
others would continue to act as agents, or that agent only brokers might not
survive. It might also be that the removal of the agency restriction might
cause a number of smaller brokers to establish links with overseas institutions
in order to set up a market making operation. Indeed this appeared to be a
concern of the Stock Exchange which submitted that to increase the number of
competitive market makers it would be necessary to attract foreign houses,
´so transferring employment and value added abroad.' Again the entry of
such overseas entities would appear likely to enhance competition in the market
and the Authority would point out that anti-competitive arrangements cannot be
justified on the basis that they keep foreign competitors out of a market.
Essentially the agency only rule prevented the emergence of market makers which
might otherwise be expected to operate in the gilt market and other forms of
dealing enterprise. Competition on the gilt market may therefore be said to
have been distorted to a degree, by the requirement that brokers act only as
agents. Consequently this provision also offended against
section 4(1).
65. The
Authority notes that the 1799 Stock Brokers Act provides that brokers must not
buy or sell on their own account when employed by any person not being a
broker. This restriction does not prevent them acting as other than an agent
when not employed by some other person. On balance therefore the Authority
concludes that the obligation contained in Rule 49.1 that brokers act only as
agents offended against
section 4(1).
(e) Applicability
of Section 4(2)
66. Under
Section 4(2), the Competition Authority may grant a licence in the case of any
agreement or category of agreements which offend against
Section 4(1) but
which, ´having regard to all relevant market conditions, contributes to
improving the production of goods or provision of services or to promoting
technical or economic progress, while allowing consumers a fair share of the
resulting benefit and which does not -
(i) impose
on the undertakings concerned terms which are not indispensable to the
attainment of those objectives;
(ii) afford
undertakings the possibility of eliminating competition in respect of a
substantial part of the products or services in question.'
(i) Minimum
Commissions
67. The
requirement that brokers charge fixed minimum commissions on transactions in
Irish Government Gilts did not satisfy the criteria set out in
Section 4(2) of
the Act for a licence, in the Authority's view. The Authority does not believe
that the rule on fixed minimum commissions contributes to improving the
distribution of goods or provision of services or to promoting technical or
economic progress. On balance it tends to accept the argument that the
abolition of fixed commissions would enhance the degree of liquidity in the
market. Consequently minimum commissions may actually hinder the further
development of the market. It accepts that brokers have in the past
contributed to the development of the market particularly when official
agencies may not have been actively developing such business. In particular it
accepts that they played a major role in attracting overseas investors into the
market. It does not believe, however, that fixed commissions were essential
for that purpose. Given that the Authority does not consider that the
arrangements lead to any efficiency benefits, consumers, in this instance the
clients of stockbrokers, by definition, do not benefit from such gains. In
fact orthodox economic theory indicates that price-fixing agreements are
detrimental rather than beneficial to consumer interests because cartels are
inefficient and lessen consumer welfare.
68. The
Authority does not believe that a system of fixed commissions is indispensable
to the continued development of the gilt market. In addition as the vast bulk
of transactions in government gilts is conducted through stockbrokers the
arrangements afford the undertakings involved the possibility of eliminating
competition in respect of a substantial part of the market in question. As all
four elements of
section 4(2) must be satisfied before a licence may be granted
the notified arrangements do not meet the requirements for a licence.
69. In
coming to the conclusion that the fixed minimum commission rules do not satisfy
the criteria for a licence the Authority took account of the fact that over a
period of 30 years the EU Commission has virtually never exempted price-fixing
arrangements from the prohibition contained in Article 85(1).
1[8]
It can see no reason for departing from well established EU precedents in the
present case. It is also relevant that price-fixing is generally prohibited
under the competition laws of most developed economies.
(ii) The
Agent Only Rule.
70. In
the case of Rule 49.1 that brokers act only as agents the Authority considers
that this can contribute to technical and economic progress and indeed accepts
that the agency system contributed to the development of the market over the
past decade. It believes that consumers in the form of investors have shared
in such benefits. It does not, however, believe that the restriction is
essential for the development of the market and so it cannot be regarded as
indispensable. The Authority does not believe that the restriction affords the
undertakings concerned the possibility of eliminating competition in respect of
a substantial part of the market. Nevertheless as it did not meet all four of
the requirements specified for the grant of a licence, the Authority was unable
to grant a licence to this restriction.
The
Decision.
71. The
Irish Stock Exchange is an association of undertakings since all of its member
firms are themselves undertakings being engaged in the provision of services
for gain. The Rules and Regulations of the Irish Stock Exchange, including
those relating to transactions in Irish Government Securities, constitute
decisions of an association of undertakings and agreements between
undertakings. In the Authority's opinion the following Rules, namely:
Rule
49.1 which required that brokers act only as agents in respect of transactions
in Irish Government securities;
Rule
75.1 which required brokers to charge fixed minimum rates of commission on such
transactions;
Rule
78.1 which set out fixed minimum rates of commission which had to be applied to
such transactions;
Rule
79.1 and 2 and Rule 81 which provided for lower rates of commission in certain
limited circumstances;
had
as their object and effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of
competition in the market for Government securities within the State and thus
offended against
section 4(1). They did not, in the opinion of the Authority,
satisfy the requirements for a licence set out in
section 4(2). Consequently
the Authority refuses to issue a certificate or grant a licence to the Irish
Stock Exchange Rules in respect of Irish Government securities, (CA/199/92E),
notified on 29 September 1992.
72.
The rule on fixed commission has now been abolished by the Irish Stock
Exchange. The present decision is not concerned with any new rules which might
be introduced by the Irish Stock Exchange in respect of dealings in Government
Gilts as no such arrangements have been notified to it. The Authority has not
considered the proposals made by the Irish Association of Investment Managers
to replace Rule 49.1. The Authority's role is to consider whether arrangements
notified to it by the parties involved offend against
section 4(1) and, when
they do, whether they meet the requirements for a licence under
section 4(2).
For
the Competition Authority
Patrick
Massey
Member
10
June 1994
Annex
1: Irish Stock Exchange Member Firms.
B.C.P.
Stockbrokers, 72 Upper Leeson Street, Dublin 2.
Bloxham
Stockbrokers, 9-12 Fleet Street, Dublin 2.
Butler
& Briscoe, 3 College Green, Dublin 2.
Campbell
O'Connor & Co., 8 Cope Street, Dublin 2.
Davy
Stockbrokers, 49 Dawson Street, Dublin 2.
Goodbody
Stockbrokers, 5 College Green, Dublin 2
Money
Markers International, Stockbrokers Ltd, 26 Lower Baggot Street, Dublin 2
W
& R Morrogh, 74 South Mall, Cork
NCB
Stockbrokers Ltd., 45/53 Lower Mount Street, Dublin 2
O'Brien
Stokes Stockbrokers, 36 Dame Street, Dublin 2
Riada
Stockbrokers, 1 College Green, Dublin 2
Solomons
Stockbrokers, Stephen Court, 18/21 St Stephens Green, Dublin 2.
1. Within
the past few weeks one of the smaller broking firms has announced that it is
relinquishing its seat on the Exchange.
3. C.
Bellamy and G. Child (1987); 'Common Market Law of Competiton', 3rd edition,
Sweet & Maxwell, London, para. 2-032.
4. See
Milchforderungsfonds, case no, 85/76/EEC, OJ L35/35, 7.2.85.
5. Bellamy
and Child, at para. 2-031.
6. ibid.
at para 4-002
7. ibid.
at para 4-003.
8. I.
Van Bael and J.F. Bellis, 'Competition Law of the EEC', 2nd edition, CCH
Editions Limited, para. 802.
9. Commission
Decision of 13 December 1985, OJ L369/25, 31.12.85. The omitted section of the
quotation describes the actual commission rates set.
10. See,
for example, Commission Decisions of 13 December 1985 in respect of; London
Cocoa Terminal Market Association Limited, Coffee Terminal Market Association
of London Limited and London Rubber Terminal Market Association Limited, OJ
L369/28 et. seq., 31.12.85. See also Commission Decisions of 10 December 1986
in respect of; The GAFTA Soya Bean Meal Futures Association, The London Grain
Futures Market, The London Potato Futures Association Limited and the London
Meat Futures Exchange Limited, OJ L19/18 et. seq., 21.1.87.
11. Case
no. 75/497/EEC, OJ L228/3, 29.8.75.
12. ibid.
p. 10.
13. ibid.
p.12.
14. Case
no. 8/72, [1972], ECR 977, point 23.
15. NV
IAZ International Belgium and Others v EC Commission, Case nos. 96-102, 104,
105, 108 and 110/82, [1983] ECR pp.3369-3430, point 3. This restated a view
which the Court had expressed in a number of previous cases.
16. United
States v Trenton Potteries Company et. al., 273 US 392 (1927).
17. United
States v Socony-Vacuum Oil Company, Inc. et. al., 310 US 150 (1940).
18. In
Uniform Eurocheques an exemption was granted for an agreement on uniform
commission charges among the banks operating the Eurocheque system, (OJ 1985
L35/43 [1985] CMLR 434). In Nuovo Cegam an exemption was granted to an
agreement between Italian engineering insurers on basic premiums to be charged,
for exceptional reasons, but this did not extend to total premiums, (OJ 1984
L99/29 [1984] 2 CMLR 484).
© 1994 Irish Competition Authority
BAILII:
Copyright Policy |
Disclaimers |
Privacy Policy |
Feedback |
Donate to BAILII
URL: http://www.bailii.org/ie/cases/IECompA/1994/335.html